GET THE APP

Time Inconsistent Stochastic Differential Game: Theory and an Example in Insurance
..

Business and Economics Journal

ISSN: 2151-6219

Open Access

Research - (2022) Volume 13, Issue 2

Time Inconsistent Stochastic Differential Game: Theory and an Example in Insurance

Hong Mao1, Krzysztof Ostaszewski2*, Zhongkai Wen3 and Jin Wang4
*Correspondence: Krzysztof Ostaszewski, Distinguished Professor of Mathematics and Actuarial Program Director, Illinois State University Normal, Illinois, USA, Tel: + 13092871711, Email:
1Shanghai Second Polytechnic University, Pudong, Shanghai, China
2Distinguished Professor of Mathematics and Actuarial Program Director, Illinois State University Normal, Illinois, USA
3University of Illinois, Chicago, USA
4Office of Information Security of China, China

Received: 10-Feb-2022, Manuscript No. bej-22-54067; Editor assigned: 12-Feb-2022, Pre QC No. P-54067; Reviewed: 18-Feb-2022, QC No. Q-54067; Revised: 24-Feb-2022, Manuscript No. R-22-54067; Published: 28-Feb-2022 , DOI: 10.37421/2151-6219.2022.13.366
Citation: Hong Mao, Krzysztof Ostaszewski, Zhongkai Wen and Jin Wang. Time Inconsistent Stochastic Differential Game: Theory and an Example in Insurance. Bus Econ J 13 (2022): 366.
Copyright: © 2022 Ostaszewski K, et al. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.

Abstract

In this paper, we study the retention and investment strategy in a time-inconsistent model for optimal decision problem under stochastic differential game framework. The investment portfolio includes multi-risky assets, whose returns are assumed to be correlated in a time-varying manner and change cyclically. The claim losses of insurance companies and investment are also assumed to be correlated with each other. Extended HJBI equations result in a solution to the portion of retention and an optimal portfolio with equally weighted allocations of risky assets, which is demonstrated first time theoretically. An optimal control bound is proposed for monitoring and predicting the optimal wealth level. The proposed model is expected to be effective in making decision for investment and reinsurance strategies, controlling, and predicting optimal wealth under uncertain environment. In particular, the model can be applied easily in the case of very high dimensional investment portfolio.

Keywords

Stochastic differential game • Time-varying correlation • Extended HJBI equation • Equally weighted investment strategy • Investment and reinsurance

Introduction

The optimal-decision problem in investment and reinsurance has attracted many attentions from academia and industry. Most literatures use time-consistent dynamic programming, establish, and solve Hamilton–Jacobi– Bellman (HJB) equations to obtain optimal solutions. Browne studied optimal investment decisions for a firm with an uncontrollable stochastic cash flow. Applied Cramer-Lundberg model for the risk process of an insurance company and used Geometric Brownian motion to model the investment in a risky asset (market index) from the surplus of the insurance company (as a measure of wealth of the insurance company). Studied optimal investment strategies for an insurance company receiving a constant-rate premium and used compound Poisson process to model the total claims to minimize the probability of ruin of insurance company. Browne (2001) studied two investors with different and possibly correlated investment opportunities under stochastic dynamic investment games in continuous time. The work of by introducing the worstcase portfolio optimization (with a market crash) in exponential utility of terminal wealth. Discussed the optimal proportional reinsurance and investment with multiple risky assets and no short positions.

Cao and Wan studied the optimal proportional reinsurance and investment strategies with Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation. Minimized the convex risk of the terminal wealth of a market portfolio with a risk-free asset and a risky asset on a jump diffusion market under stochastic differential game. used similar stochastic differential game to model the relationship between an insurance company and the market; they used Max-Min strategy on the expectation for the utility of the terminal wealth to get the optimal investment and reinsurance strategy under uncertain environment. Applied the same differential game as in Zhang and Siu on the time-consistent optimization problem of retention and multiple-type loss-independent investment portfolio under uncertain environment. All the studies above have several limitations: (1) most of them considered only one risky asset and non-negative return rate due to the Geometric Brownian assumption for the return rate; (2) investment and the claim loss are considered to be independent processes except a few studies. Most of the previous studies applied time-consistent dynamic programming. However, it is usually the case that risky assets invested in capital market are correlated with each other; the investment returns are generally cyclical changing and can be negative sometimes, in fact, the return rates of investment funds in stock markets can be negative, especially at the time when economy experiences recession or crisis; the investment and claim loss may be correlated with each other; insurance companies are generally ongoing business and their surplus at terminal time is state-dependent and time-consistency is not satisfied due to non-Markovian setting.

The time-inconsistency of stochastic optimization problem is not allowed for a Bellman optimality principle. The following for the first time, proposed multi-variate Vasicek model with time-varying correlation for the return rates of multi-risky assets of Defined Benefit pension plan, but the time-inconsistency doesn’t play any role in their model. Obtained a general stochastic Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation for general coupled system of forward-backward stochastic differential equations with jumps. Applied timeinconsistent stochastic control in continuous time within a theoretical game framework and extended the standard Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation to obtain the solution of the strategy and the value function at the equilibrium [1-22].

This paper establishes a time-inconsistent model under stochastic differential game framework with time-varying correlated risky assets. HBJI equation is established with loosened conditions of standard HBJI equation and state-dependent value function at terminal time. The solution of the extended HJBI equation results in optimal strategy of the portion of retention and equal weighted risky-asset investment. Control bound is proposed for monitoring and predicting the optimal wealth level for a finite time horizon. In fact, insurance companies are generally going concern businesses, and their life term is uncertain, hence it is difficult to determine their surplus at a terminal time. When wealth level is close to the lower bound or tends to move to the lower bound, the adjustment needs to be taken and new decision should be made based on the adjustment. The model presented in this paper is effective in the decision-making of investment and reinsurance strategies and in the control and prediction of optimal wealth under uncertain environment.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: section 2 gives the insurance and investment models; section 3 gives the extended Hamilton- Jacobi-Bellman-Isaacs (HJBI) equation and solution for the optimal investment and reinsurance strategies; section 4 presents results of our numerical analyses; section 5 concludes this paper.

Methodology

The insurance and investment models

The following presents the notation we use:

C(t): Risk process of an insurer at time t

R(t): The surplus process (excluding investment) of insurance company at time t

α(t): The proportion of retention of proportional reinsurance at time t

p0: The net premium rate

δ: The safety loading of insurance premium

η:The safety loading of reinsurance premium

W1(t): The Brownian Motion for claim loss

W2(t): The Brownian motion for investment return rate

σD: The standard deviation of claim loss

αi(t): The proportions of the risky asset in investment portfolio at time t

Xt: the surplus or wealth of the insurer at time t

(t): the amount of risky-asset investment

rf: the risk free interest rate

ri(t): Return rate for risky assets i at time t

Let C(t): be modeled is a manner similar to Promislow and Young (2005):

image (1)

and let surplus process R(t) be modeled as

image (2)

Where η ≥ δ.

Note that the Brownian motion model (continuous) of the claim process is the limit of the discrete compound Poisson model [8]. Borrowing at the risk-free interest rate is not allowed, i.e., Xt is not allowed to be negative for all t≥0, the amount invested in risky assets cannot be greater than the wealth level. Let (t) be the amount invested in risky assets.

Assume that the return process of risky asset ri(t) for i=1,2,…,n, at time follows the [23,24]. Stochastic process: π

image (3)

Where ri the return is rate of the i-th risky asset, and wi2 (t), i=1,2,…,n, are mutually dependent standard Wiener process defined on (Ω,F,{Ft}t≥0,P). For simplicity, it is assumed that the underlying filtration, Ft coincides with one generated by the Wiener process, that is, Ft =σ(W2(s):0≤s≤t) and σ denotes the volatility matrix.

If mi=m, then we have:

image (4)

The return of investment portfolio can be described with Vasicek model as:

image (5)

where σr is in instantaneous volatility of randomness measure of the return rate of investment portfolio, br is the long term equilibrium return rate of investment portfolio, br - r is the gap between its current rate of return and its long-run equilibrium level and m is a parameter measuring the speed at which the gap diminishes. The diversified portfolio consists of n types of risky investments, the fraction invested in i-th risky investment is ai, i=1,2,…,n, or α = (α1, α2, ...αn) and The return on risky asset i follows stochastic differential equation (3) and the return rate of the portfolio of risky assets is

image (6)

The differential of the portfolio return of risky assets is

image (7)

If the correlation between zi and zj, pij then the variance of the portfolio return is

image (8)

And the standard deviation is

image (9)

As in Momon (2004), the expected return rate of risky investment portfolio is

image (10)

Where μi(t) is the expected return rate of i-th risky asset at time in real world measure and ri(0) is the return rate of i-th risky investment at t=0. Let

image (11)

where σi2(t) is the volatility of the return rate of i-th risky asset under the real world measure,

image (12)

And σij(t) is covariance between i-th risky asset and j-th asset under the real world measure,

image (13)

For the proof of equation (13), please see Appendix A.

Based on Mamon (2004), image also satisfies the stochastic differential equation: image, where Bi is i-dimensional standard Brownian Motion, i=1,2,…,n, and the return rate of risky investment portfolio r(t) satisfies

image (14)

Let image be the wealth process of the insurance company for the strategy . The insurer uses the self-financing strategy. Based on equations of (2) and (14), insurer’s wealth follows the equation below:

image (15)

With a boundary condition of image, and

image (16)

where 1 {Br(t), W1(t) / t≥0} are standard Brownian motions on a filtered probability space (Ω,F, {Ft} t≥0, P), Ft is the P-augmentation of the natural filtration, ρ is the coefficient of correlation between Br(t) and W1(t) and ρ≤0; the total amount invested in risky investment, Ξ(t), is a measurable control process adapted to the filtration {Ft}t≥0, satisfying:

image (17)

Assume that α(t) is a non-negative measurable process adapted to the filtration {Ft}t≤0, satisfying equation (15), that is,

image (18)

And the wealth equation (15) has unique optimal solutions of ((t),a(t),a(t))..

Extension of HJBI equation and solutions of optimal investment and retention of reinsurance

We let Dθ be the set of admissible controls by the market and let π for the set of admissible strategies ϑ=(Ξ,a,α) of the insurance company. For any T<∞, a process {θ(t) / t∈[0,T]} satisfies the condition of image and (t) ≤ 1. For each θεD, F-adapted process image is a real-valued process defined on (Ω,F, {Ft}t≥0, P) as:

image (19)

By Ito’s differentiation rule, we obtain

image (20)

Where image local martingale, and satisfies image For each θεΘD, a new (real-world) probability measure Pθ, which is absolutely continuous with respect to P, is defined on (Ω,F(T)) by

image (21)

The optimal problem of the insurance company can be formulated as a two-player, zero-sum, stochastic differential game as in [7]. The measure θ is the control of one player (the “market”), while the investment portfolio and retention of reinsurance (Ξa,) is the control of player two (the insurer). We define a vector process by:

image (22)

The optimization problem is formulated to Min-Max expectation for the utility of the terminal wealth. Given the initial time, t0, the initial wealth of the insurer, X0, the objective function over the class of admissible controls (θ,)ε(Θxπ) is given by

image (23)

In a manner similar to the work in [25] the process A(t) is defined as

image

Where image and μr(s) and σr(s). Satisfy equations (10) and (11), respectively. Therefore μr(t). in stochastic differential equation (15) can be replaced by λ(t)σr(t). Then performance process is defined to be dependent on A(t) and image as:

image

Where image is defined by equation (15) and image is defined by equation (19).

Since image, the utility does not really depend on A(T), we can transform the utility of state-dependence into the one with state-independence. Although the utility at terminal time is state-independent, it is difficult to assure that the performance process defined by equation (24) satisfies time-consistent condition at the whole state space (Θxπ).

Therefore, the defined form of image may not be suitable for dynamic programming. We here assume that our performance process image doesn’t satisfy time consistency and the control can be restricted only to admissible feedback control. Our objective is to min-max image for each (t, v1, v2), which can be proved to be the case in theorem 1. Our optimal control is not strictly optimal based on the dynamics of the process. However, for any twice continuously differential function image, where image denotes the closure of O, there exists a partial differential operator image

image

According to Mataramvura and Âksendal (2008) and Bjork T, et al. [15], it is not

Difficult to get the following verification theorem

Theorem 1: Suppose that there exists a function image , a function g(T,t) and an admissible feedback control image such that

image

4. The value function is determined by extended HBJI defined by equation (27).

5. since image, for all

image

6. Let K denote the set of stopping times τ ≤ T. The family image is uniform integral for all image

Then image is an optimal control [26,27]. Proof:

First, the value function is proved to be determined by extended HBJI equation as followings. The Ito formula is applied to the performance process image. Expectation of the integration yields:

image

Where the stochastic integral part has vanished because of the integrability Then, image

Therefore, we obtain the desired result:

image

Second (θ*,*) is proved to be the supremum in the value function and is proved to be an admissible feedback control as follows.

Choose (θ,)εΘD xπ, then, for h>0, a randomly chosen initial state (t,v1,v2) and define the control law (θhh) as

image

Furthermore, we obtain:

image

Since image, we have

image

Then we obtain

image

Furthermore, from equation (23) we have image.

It gives us that image Combining this with expression for image above and the fact that image

We obtain image

image

Similarly, we obtain:

image

Then we have

image

Furthermore, from equation (23) we have image. It gives us that

image

Combining this with expression for image above and the fact that

image

We obtain image.

So image

Then, image.

This finishes the proof.

The optimal investment problem is formulated to Min-Max expectation of the exponential utility of the terminal wealth of an insurance company. Since the utility function is dependent on the present states of v=(t,v1,v2), the condition of HJBI equation is not satisfied. In order to obtain the optimal value function φ*(v,A(t)) and the optimal strategy (θ*,Ξ*,a*θ*), an extended HJBI equation is built as follows which is similar to Bjork T, et al. [7]

image (26)

A value function of exponential form as in (27) is taken to solve the equation above.

image (27)

Where γ is the coefficient of risk aversion, g(T-s) is an undetermined function with image and the boundary condition: g(T-T)=1.

ϑ=(a,θ) and substitution of value function (27) into equation (26) result in the differential operator:

image (28)

We cannot show from equation (27) that

image

Due to the following facts: from equation (30), we will know that it is not always the case that image

image

Therefore, we can only construct the extended HJBI equation because acceptable time-consistence cannot be satisfied. Combination of equation (28) and equation (26) leads to extended HJBI equation (29) as following:

image (29)

image

Equations (29) and (30) indicate that φD(s,v1,v2) ≠1 is the sufficient and necessary condition for the existence of optimal solutions [1]. It is necessary to make v1 and v2 different from zero [8]. Maximization over (Ξa,) with fixed

θ∈ΘD leads to the following first order conditions for the maximum point ((θ),a(θ),a(θ)) as equations of (31), (32) and (34), respectively:

image (31)

image (32)

image (33)

Since equation (33) can be written as following simplified form

image

(Please note that the following equal weights is deducted from the non-partially differential θ related term, θ and other non-partially differential θ related terms in right hand side of equation (33)) and at the same time, the constraint condition image is satisfied as well.

It is implied that only when a1=a2=…,=an-1 and a2=a3=…,=an can the equation (33) hold. Therefore, we have optimal proportions of risky assets invested satisfy:

image (34)

That is, optimal proportion of risky assets invested is equally weighted when n≥3.

Putting equation (34) into equations of (10) and (11), respectively, we have

image (35)

image (36)

Although equally weighted investment strategy is usually thought of as a feasible and convenient investment strategy, it has never been demonstrated theoretically to be an optimal investment strategy under some conditions. Here our theoretical proof has demonstrated the possibility of the equal-weight investment as an optimal strategy. It is especially important to notice that equal weights can simplify greatly the optimization process.

Combination of equations (31) and (32) with equations (29) and (30) and Minimization over θ result in equation (37):

image (37)

where image, and

image

We can easily obtain the optimal solution of (t) by solving equation (37) with the equally weighted investment portfolio. Putting optimal solution of θ into equations (31) and (32), results in the optimal amount invested in risky assets and the optimal

Portion of retention of reinsurance = image.

The optimal wealth process can be expressed as:

image (38)

image (39)

Where p is the net premium rate and p0 is the claim loss rate.

The lower control bound with (1-ϖ) confidential level is obtained by combining equations (38) and (39) as following:

image (40)

Where LCL(t) is lower bound of wealth at time t(t ≤ T, and T is control period), image is deviation of optimal wealth, mϖ is the critical value with 1(-ϖ) confidential level, while μr and σr satisfy equations (10), (11) and (34), respectively.

Equation (40) is obtained as following by combining equation (31), (32) and (38) with equation (28), using t instead of s and setting it equal to 0:

image (41)

where

image(42)

and

image (43)

Integration of two sides of equation (42) and application of the boundary condition g(T,λT)=1 sult in the formula for g(t):

image (44)

image

We also analyze the case when â(θ,t)≤0. If â(θ,t)≤0, we should choose â(θ,t)=0 as an optimal strategy. Substitution of â=0 into equation (30) results in equation (48):

image (45)

Maximization over π with fixed θ∈ΘD leads to the following first order condition for the maximum point (θ).

image (46)

With â=0 and in combination of equation (46) with equation (45), minimization over θ results in the first order condition for the minimum point, where: θ=θ.

image (47)

Equation (46) and equation (47) lead to equation (48):

image (48)

Substitution of â =0, equations (47) and (48) into equation (45) with ø(s,v1,v2)≠0 results in equation (49):

image (49)

where

image

Therefore, analysis above implies the following theorem.

Theorem 2

image

The optimal strategy (θ*,*, θ*)=(θΞ,θ, θ) is given by equations (31), (32), (34) and (37), and the optimal value function is:

image(50)

Where g(T-t) is given by equation (44).

When a(t)=0, the optimal strategy (θ*,Ξ*, θ*)=(θΞ,θ) is given by equations (47), (48) and (34). The optimal value function satisfies equation (50) where g(T-t) is given by equation (49).

Results and Discussion

Numerical analysis

The data of annual return rate of S & P 500, Treasury Bonds and Treasury Bills in U.S. from 1965 to 2014 is used in multi-variate Vasicek model. The results are displayed in Table 1. Please note that Table 1 includes the estimated values of three parameters and asymptotic errors of both Vasicek models [28].

Table 1: The values of parameters and asymptotic error of Vasicek model estimated using historical data in U.S. from 1965 to 2014.

MLE S&P Estimation
error
Treasury
Bond
Estimation
error
Treasury
Bill
Estimation
error
Estimation(mi) 4.9677 0.2389 2.4594 0.0654 0.1664 0.0085
Estimation(bi) 0.1134 0.0240 0.0985 0.0221 0.0509 0.0042
Estimation(σi) 0.5348 0.2624 0.3473 0.0248 0.0171  

For other data, please see Table 2. Table 3 lists optimal solutions of amount invested in risky assets, Ξ*, portion of retention, a1* and proportions of stocks, Treasury Bonds and Treasury Bills a1*, a2* and a3*. Table 3 lists the optimal solutions for different time t. Table 3 indicates that the optimal amount invested in risky assets first decreases and then increases with time, but the optimal portion of retention first increases and then decreases with time. Of course, the optimal solutions can be obtained for other terminal time T. Since insurance business is generally on-going business, which means that the life time is uncertain, it is important to obtain the optimal solutions for varying terminal time. In the following section, sensitivity analyses are carried out to the changes of the important parameters.

Table 2: Other values of parameters in the example.

Parameters Values
The coefficient of correlation        ρ -0.2
The average rate of claim loss     p0 0.15
The volatility of claim loss            σD 0.21
The coefficient of risk aversion      у 2
The net premium rate                   p  0.15
The loading of premium               δ 0.05
The cost rate of reinsurance       η  0.1
The initial investment               X(0) 1
The terminal time                      T  15

Table 3: The optimal solutions when time t changes.

t 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
3.237 3.132 3.164 3.202 3.235 3.264 3.288 3.308  
a*= 0.573 0.561 0.564 0.568 0.572 0.575 0.577 0.579
t 9 10 11 12 13 14 15  
3.325 3.34 3.352 3.362 3.371 3.379 3.385    

Varying parameters of σD, η and γ

Figure 1(a) displays the change pattern of time-varying correlation among risky assets invested. Figure 1(b) through (g) shows the change patterns of optimal solutions of the amount invested in risky assets and the optimal portion of the retention for different values of the volatility of claim loss, σD, the rate of (e) indicate that increase in the rate of reinsurance cost will greatly decrease the optimal amount invested in risky assets but greatly increase optimal portion of the retention. Figure 1(f) and Figure 1(g) show that both optimal amount of investment and optimal retention decreases with the increase of risk aversion, which is intuitive (Figures 1a-1g).

business-economics-journal-assets-invested

Figure 1a. Time-varying correlation among risky assets invested.

business-economics-journal-claim-loss

Figure 1b. The optimal amount invested in risky assets for different values of the volatility of claim loss over time.

business-economics-journal-volatility-claim

Figure 1c. The optimal portion of the retention for different values of the volatility of claim loss over time.

business-economics-journal-risky-assets

Figure 1d. The optimal amount invested in risky assets for different values of the rate of reinsurance cost over time.

business-economics-journal-optimal-portion

Figure 1e. The optimal portion of the retention for different values of the rate of reinsurance cost over time.

business-economics-journal-risky-assets

Figure 1f. The optimal amount invested in risky assets for different values of the coefficient of risk aversion over time.

business-economics-journal-risk-aversion

Figure 1g. The optimal portion of the retention for different values of the coefficient of risk aversion over time.

Varying parameters of σi and bi,i=1,2,3.

Figures 2(a) through (d) display the change patterns of optimal solutions of the amount invested in risky assets and the optimal portion of the retention with the change of volatilities and the means of long term return of risky assets invested, σi and bi,i=1,2,3. Figures 2(a) and (b) indicate that both optimal reinsurance cost, η, and the coefficient of risk aversion, γ Figure 1(b) and (c) indicate that both the optimal amount invested in risky assets and the optimal portion of the retention decreases with the increase of the volatility of claim loss. The increase of the risk of claim loss tends to make the insurer more willing to increase reinsurance and put less funds in risky assets. Figure 1(d) and amount invested in risky assets and retention portion are greater when the volatility of the return of the stocks, Treasury Bonds and Treasury Bills decrease 10%, respectively; especially they are much more sensitive to the increase in the volatility of the return of stocks and Treasury Bonds than that of Treasury Bills, that is to say, lower volatility of the return of risky assets invested will encourage insurers to put more funds in investment, and more remains for retention of reinsurance. Figures 2(c) and (d) indicate that the optimal amount invested in risky assets increases and the optimal portion of the retention also increases when the means of long term return of the stocks, Treasury Bonds and Treasury Bills increase 10%, respectively; the optimal amount of stocks and Treasury Bonds are much more sensitive to the change of the means of long term return of stocks and Treasury Bonds than to that of Treasury Bills; and the optimal retention is also sensitive to the means of long term returns of all of three kinds of long term risky assets (Figures 2a-2d).

business-economics-journal-risky-assets

Figure 2a. The optimal amount invested in risky assets for different values of the volatility of risky assets over time (ρ=-0.2).

business-economics-journal-risky-assets

Figure 2b. The optimal portion of the retention for different values of the volatility of risky assets over time (ρ=-0.2).

business-economics-journal-risky-assets

Figure 2c. The optimal amount invested in risky assets for different values of the means of long-term return of risky assets over time (ρ=-0.2).

business-economics-journal-optimal-portion

Figure 2d. The optimal portion of the retention for different values of the means of long-term return of risky assets over time (ρ=-0.2).

Figure 3(a) through Figure 3(d) display the change patterns of optimal amount investment and optimal retention portions when the correlation coefficient between investment and investment return rate of long term and volatility changes. Figure 3(a) through Figure 3(d) show that the optimal amount of risky investment decreases with the increase of correlation coefficient between investments and claim loss. However, optimal retention portion of reinsurance at first increases with the increase of correlation coefficients and then decreases with the increase of correlation coefficients (Figures 3a-3d).

business-economics-journal-risky-assets

Figure 3a. The optimal amount invested in risky assets for different values of the correlation coefficient between investment and claim loss over time (b1 and b1(1-0,1).

business-economics-journal-claim-loss

Figure 3b. The optimal portion of the retention for different values of the correlation coefficient between investment and claim loss over time (b1 and b1(1-0,1).

business-economics-journal-claim-loss

Figure 3c. The optimal amount invested in risky assets for different values of the correlation coefficient between investment and claim loss over time (σ1 and σ1(1-0.1).

business-economics-journal-optimal-portion

Figure 3d. The optimal portion of the retention for different values of the correlation coefficient between investment and claim loss over time (σ1 and σ1(1-0.1).

Conclusion

In this paper, the optimal decision of investment and reinsurance is studied with time-inconsistence under the stochastic differential game framework. Multiple risky assets constitute investment portfolios; the returns of these risky assets follow multi-variate Vasicek model with time-varying correlation; claim losses are correlated with these risky assets. The solution to the extended HJBI equation results in dynamical optimal solutions for the amount invested in risky assets, the optimal portion of the retention and optimal proportions of all risky assets invested. A dynamical optimal bound is built for monitoring and predicting the optimal wealth level. The numerical analyses are carried out under the proposed model. The sensitivity analyses indicate that the optimal amount invested in risky assets in the proposed model are sensitive to most of the parameters except the volatility and the means of the Treasury Bills return at the long-run equilibrium; the optimal portion of the retention is sensitive to all of parameters The volatility and the means of long term returns of all three kinds of risky assets. Our sensitive analysis results are consistent to intuitions, and this demonstrates the effectiveness of our proposed model. Importantly, the investment with equally weighted risky assets can be an optimal strategy. The proposed model can be easily applied in very high dimension investment portfolio.

Appendix

We calculate the time varying covariance of σij (t) of the return of stocks and bonds. In a manner similar to Korn and Koziol (2006), and Mamon (2004).

image

In the following, we calculate the time varying covariance, σij (t), By Itô isometry, we have:

image

References

  1. Browne, Sid. “Optimal investment policies for a firm with a random risk process: exponential utility and minimizing the probability of ruin”. Math of Oper Res 20 (1995):937-958.
  2. Google Scholar, Crossref

  3. Hipp, Christian and Michael Plum. “Optimal investment for insurers”. Insurance: J Math Econ 27 (2000):215-228.
  4. Google Scholar, Crossref

  5. Liu, Chi Sang and Hailiang Yang. “Optimal investment for an insurer to minimize its probability of ruin”. North Amer Actuarial J 8 (2004):11-31.
  6. Google Scholar, Crossref

  7. Korn, Ralf. “Worst-case scenario investment for insurers”. Insurance: J Math Econ 31 (2005):1-11.
  8. Google Scholar, Crossref

  9. Bai, Lihua and Junyi Guo. “Optimal proportional reinsurance and investment with multiple risky assets and no-shorting constraint”. Insurance: J Math Econ 42 (2008):968-975.
  10. Google Scholar, Crossref

  11. Cao, Yusong and Nianqing Wan. “Optimal proportional reinsurance and investment based on Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation”. Insurance: J Math Econ 45 (2009):157-162.
  12. Google Scholar, Crossref

  13. Mataramvura, Sure and Bernt Øksendal. “Risk minimizing portfolios and HJBI equations for stochastic differential games”. Stochastics: An Inter J Prob Stochas Proc 80 (2008):317-337.
  14. Google Scholar, Crossref

  15. Zhang, Xin and Tak Kuen Siu. “Optimal investment and reinsurance of an insurer with model uncertainty”. Insurance: J Math Econ 45 (2009):81-88.
  16. Google Scholar, Crossref

  17. Mao, Hong, James M. Carson, Krzysztof M. Ostaszewski, Yan Luo and Yuling Wang. “Determining the insurer’s optimal investment and reinsurance strategy based on stochastic differential game”. J Insur Issue 39 (2016):187-202.
  18. Google Scholar, Crossref

  19. Hong, Mao, Ostaszewski Krzysztof, Yuling Wang and Zhongkai Wen. “Determination of optimal contribution rate and optimal investment portfolio of defined benefit pension plan under the expected shortfall constraint.” Pub Risk Manag: Persp Theory and Pract (2016).
  20. Google Scholar 

  21. Mamon, Rogemar S. “Three ways to solve for bond prices in the Vasicek model”. J Appl Math Deci Sci 8 (2004):1-14.
  22. Google Scholar 

  23. Korn, Olaf and Christian Koziol. “Bond portfolio optimization: A risk-return approach”. J Fixed Income 15 (2006):48-60.
  24. Google Scholar, Crossref

  25. Øksendal, Bernt, Agnes Sulem and Tusheng Zhang. “A stochastic HJBI equation for optimal control of forward-backward SDEs”.  (2016):435-446.
  26. Google Scholar, Crossref

  27. Podolskij, Mark, Robert Stelzer, Steen Thorbjørnsen and Almut ED Veraart, eds. “The Fascination of Probability, Statistics and Their Applications”. In Honour of Ole E. Barndorff-Nielsen. Springer (2015).
  28. Google Scholar

  29. Bjork, Tomas, Mariana Khapko and Agatha Murgoci. “On time inconsistent stochastic control in continuous time”. Fin and Stochastics 21 (2017):331-336.
  30. Google Scholar

  31. Yang, Hailiang and Lihong Zhang. “Optimal investment for insurer with jump-diffusion risk process”, Insurance: J Math Econ 37 (2005):613-634.
  32. Google Scholar, Crossref

  33. Mao, Hong and Zhongkai Wen. “Optimal dynamic insurance price and investment portfolio of an insurer with multi-dimensional time-varying correlation”. J Quant Eco Forthcoming (2016).
  34. Google Scholar, Crossref

  35. Browne, Sid. “Stochastic differential portfolio games”. J Applied Prob. 37 (2000):126-147.
  36. Google Scholar, Crossref

  37. Korn, Ralf and Frank Thomas Seifried. “A worst-case approach to continuous-time portfolio Optimization”. Radon Ser. Comp Appl Math 8 (2009):327-345.
  38. Google Scholar, Crossref

  39. Korn, Ralf, Olaf Menkens and Mogens Steffensen, “Worst-case-optimal dynamic reinsurance for large claim”. Eur Actuarial J 2 (2012):21-48.
  40. Google Scholar, Crossref

  41. David Promislow S., and Virginia R. Young. “Minimizing the probability of ruin when claims follow Brownian motion with drift”. N Am Actuar J 9 (2005):109-128.
  42. Google Scholar, Crossref

  43. Aase, Knut K. “The investment horizon problem: A resolution”.  NHH Depart of Fin & Manag Sci Disc Pap (2009).
  44. Google Scholar, Crossref

  45. Vasicek, Oldrich. “An equilibrium characterization of the term structure”. J Math Econ 5 (1977):177-188.
  46. Google Scholar, Crossref

  47. Lim, Byung Hwa., and Yong Hyun Shin. “Optimal investment, consumption, and retirement decision with disutility and borrowing constraints”. J Quant Fin 11 (2011):1581-1592.
  48. Google Scholar, Crossref

  49. Musiela, Marek and Thaleia Zariphopoulou. “Portfolio choice under dynamic investment performance criteria”, J Quant Fin 9 (2009):1-19.
  50. Google Scholar, Crossref

  51. Bielecki, Tomasz R., Igor Cialenco and Marcin Pitera. “On time consistency of dynamic risk and performance measures indiscrete time”. Working paper 2014.
  52. Google Scholar

  53. Fleming, Wendell H., and Raymond W Rishel. “Deterministic and Stochastic Optimal Control”. Spinger-Verlag New York, Inc. (1975).
  54. Google Scholar

  55. Gourieroux, Christian and Joann Jasiak. “Financial Econometrics”. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. (2001).
  56. Google Scholar

Google Scholar citation report
Citations: 5936

Business and Economics Journal received 5936 citations as per Google Scholar report

Business and Economics Journal peer review process verified at publons

Indexed In

 
arrow_upward arrow_upward